The Friendly Shopkeeper Advertising Model

The dirty little secret that nobody wants to admit, amidst the Web 2.0 crowd’s rush to monetize any piece of content that isn’t nailed to the floor, is that advertising sucks. This isn’t a new problem. Prior to the Internet, you were lucky to get 2% response rates to advertising campaigns. The magnitude of the failure of traditional advertising only became apparent when two guys from Stanford realized that you could show ads based on people’s search criteria and provide much more targeted ads. While this observation only doubled response rates to a paltry 4%, that multiple is currently responsible for the billion dollars a quarter that Google generates in revenue.

But this isn’t really an achievement to celebrate, at least, not yet.

The problem with most advertising is that, on a macro-scale, it’s almost indistinguishable from spam. Think of all the advertising that gets thrown at you on a daily basis: the flyers that show up at your door, simply because you live in a certain neighbourhood; the brochures and pullouts stuffed in magazines and newspapers that pitch you products simply because that magazine’s readership fits a certain demographic profile; and let’s not forget the billboards, the radio ads, and, yes, even the urinal posters. These woefully unwanted come-ons inadvertently communicate one unavoidable message to a consumer: that the advertiser, while desperate for your business, knows absolutely nothing about you.

There is a better model of advertising that’s coming, something I like to call the “friendly shopkeeper” model of advertising. Allow me to elaborate…

There was a time when you would go into physical store and the shopkeeper behind the counter might know your name, but more importantly, remembered the kind of stuff you’d asked about in the past, and most important of all, the stuff you had bought in the past. This, combined with the shopkeeper’s own rich and deep understanding of new products and trends in the market, would allow the shopkeeper to provide a valuable service to you: the role of a trusted advisor. This person would helpfully suggest items that might interest you – for example: a new album from a band you’d never heard of, but that resembled something else the shopkeeper knew you liked.

Of course, the shopkeeper wasn’t doing this out of philanthropy, but out of a vested interest in providing a valuable service to his customers. The shopkeeper acted as an editor, weeding out the stuff that wouldn’t interest you, and suggesting things you might like. In exchange for this service, you bought the products suggested and, if the suggestions proved worthwhile, you came back and bought more stuff based on the shopkeeper’s advice. It was structured as a win-win scenario.

This is the model of the web that we should aspire to create. While many might, as seen in recent months, decry the idea of sharing information willy-nilly (cf: the Facebook Beacon fiasco), I’m not averse to sharing that information with vendors. But there’s a catch: I want some value out of giving you that information. I don’t want more advertisements, I want less ads, and only for items that I might actually be interested in.

In many cases, we’ve come close to this model, but only in specific product categories. For example: a number of services do a great job in suggesting music, and generating affiliate revenue when the listener buys a suggested song or CD. Unfortunately, none of that information ever makes it to other vendors where it might lead to better recommendations. If, for example, I end up buying a CD at Wal-Mart.com, that information never gets used to improve my Amazon.com recommendations. Instead, I end up with a number of different vendors pitching me the same stuff again and again because they have incomplete information about me. In the simplest case, they just don’t know that I already bought that CD. That doesn’t serve their interests (it’s highly unlikely I’m going to buy the same product again and again), and it doesn’t serve mine (because I’m not getting introduced to interesting new music).

In an ideal world, online vendors would know me better than I may even know myself. They wouldn’t suggest stuff I already own. They would know my friends and what they’ve purchased. They would even have noticed who among my friends are key tastemakers and influencers on my preferences to derive even better recommendations (after all, nobody chooses friends with whom they have nothing in common). They would amalgamate all of this information wherever it lives. It would do this in an aggregate fashion that, unlike Facebook’s Beacon, doesn’t reveal my purchases directly to others but instead uses that information to feed a recommendation engine with the fuel it needs to provide personalized, customized advertising.

In the end, what I want is not advertising, but something that achieves all the goals of advertising: matching people who have something to sell with people who want to buy it, but with 100% accuracy (or, at the very least, 0% annoyance and intrusion).

(This post was inspired by something I’ve been thinking about for a while, coupled with a desperate need to beat Ian Bell to the punch on claiming the “friendly shopkeeper” metaphor, something his company is working on achieving with their Pul.se Facebook application. Disclosure: Ian is a friend. )

Sell-Side Advertising

A number of bloggers have been ruminating the future of advertising (most notably Fred Wilson, John Batelle, Seth Godin, and Adam Rifkin), mostly inspired by Ross Mayfield’s “Cost Per Influence” post from eons ago (think July – that’s, like, forever in the blogosphere). I thought it might be time to weigh in on their concept of “sell-side advertising” (closely related is Greg Linden’s discussion of “intent marketing“). The idea at the core of “sell-side advertising” is intriguing: what if advertising became less about companies and advertisers pushing out advertisements to people who didn’t care about what they’re selling, and more about allowing influencers to connect products with the people who actually want them?

From my understanding, the sell-side advertising concept is part Google AdSense and part Amazon Associates. On drugs. Batelle gives a good summary:

Instead of advertisers buying either PPC networks or specific publishers/sites, they simply release their ads to the net, perhaps on specified servers where they can easily be found, or on their own sites, and/or through seed buys on one or two exemplar sites. These ads are tagged with information supplied by the advertiser, for example, who they are attempting to reach, what kind of environments they want to be in (and environments they expressly forbid, like porn sites or affiliate sites), and how much money they are willing to spend on the ad.

It’s a great idea – let the publishers (such as bloggers) advertise to their circle of influence and get paid on performance (read: actual sales). No performance, no money! Like Amazon’s Associates, there’s little incentive for someone to create a page full of links without any value-add. Like Google AdWords, it levels the playing field, offering smaller advertisers the opportunity to reach their market without breaking the bank. Even better, it offers smaller advertisers a calculable ROI – it’s no longer a crap-shoot like it is with Google AdWords (after all, even with the best click-through rate in the industry, isn’t the click-through rate still abysmal?).

From the publisher’s point of view, this is also an especially appealing model. First and foremost, I believe the improved ability of such an advertising model to provide measurable results (in terms of actual dollars, not just “eyeballs”) would result in improved revenue for the publishers themselves – far better than per-click advertising. Heck, just compare how Amazon referral fees outweighed my author royalties!As an added bonus, such a model would put advertising control back in the hands of the publisher, thus avoiding the puzzle of Google Adwords that are totally unrelated to the content on the page.

As Seth points out, this model is already out there in the form of an offering from Commission Junction. I recall signing up for a Commission Junction account ages ago when I was exploring ways to boost my book sales – I believe Commission Junction was providing the affiliate program for Barnes & Noble. It was horrible. Bad user interface, and difficult to actually find the items I wanted to sell. Anyone know if it’s improved since last I tried it (early 2002)? Perhaps if they improved the interface and created plugins for blogging tools to streamline the process of adding affiliate links, they’d really have something.

That said, there are still some issues with such a system. For one thing, I think it’s safe to say that a large part of the blog world will be uncomfortable with the idea of the commercialization of the blogosphere. Scoble won’t even use affiliate links. And Canter (God bless him for trying stuff) probably would have been burned at the stake if he showed up at Bloggercon with his get-paid-to-blog schemes.

A shift to pure pay-for-performance advertising might have some interesting ramifications. As Hugh MacLeod loves to point out:

“But that’s always been the trouble with advertising. The money has always been in the dreck. Because the good stuff advertises itself.”

While I agree, I think the problem we’re currently facing is that there’s just too much good stuff. If the advertising market moves to a model where publishers only choose advertisements that interest their readers (if only to maintain their street cred and fend off accusations that they’re being a shill), some products’ advertisements will never see the light of day. After all, some products will never invite a religious following that will build buzz – those things are called commodities. Nobody cares enough about, for example, toothpaste to write about it (unless, of course, they screw up royally), much less participate in some Crest-sponsored affiliates program.

And that’s OK, because these products are overpriced anyway, given they have little true innovation to justify their price in light of their low input costs. But therein lies the paradox – as publishers shift towards the more lucrative world of pay-for-performance advertising, commodity producers will find it difficult to even buy themselves an audience. The question in my mind: will this drive up the price of old-world, pay-for-no-guarantee-of-performance advertisements to new heights, or will the dismal economics of these commodity products prevent them from being able to gain an audience at any price?